All Insights

Currently reading

Did imports lower US real GDP?

Investment Insights • Macro

3 min read

Did imports lower US real GDP?

Did imports lower US real GDP in the first quarter of 2025? Some commentators have pointed to a surge in demand for foreign goods as the reason for the reported contraction. In this note, EFG Chief Economist Stefan Gerlach explains why that interpretation misreads the mechanics of GDP accounting.

Stefan Gerlach
Stefan Gerlach

Macroeconomic statistics are frequently subject to misinterpretation, whether intentional or not. This risk increases during periods of political tension, particularly when economic data intersects with policy debates. The US GDP figures for the first quarter of 2025 represent a good example of such a case.

According to the advance estimate, real GDP declined at an annualised rate of 0.3% in Q1. As shown in the graph below, this marks a sharp slowdown from the 2.5% average growth recorded across the four quarters of 2024.
 

Chart 1. Real GDP growth

USGDP1.png

Source: BEA; data as of 30 April 2025.

Looking at the contributions to growth, consumption and investment, including the change in inventories, contributed positively to real GDP growth, but imports pushed it down by a roughly equal amount, leaving the contributions of government spending and exports essentially zero.

Chart 2. Contribution to change in real GDP

USGDP2.png

Source: BEA; data as of 30 April 2025.

Some observers have attributed the decline in GDP to a surge in imports, arguing that firms and households brought forward purchases of foreign goods in anticipation of new tariffs, and that without this shift, GDP would not have declined. While this explanation may seem plausible at first glance, it reflects a misunderstanding of how GDP is measured in the national accounts.

The role of imports in GDP accounting
It is useful to start by considering how GDP is measured. Real GDP captures the value of domestic goods and services produced and sold. These goods and services are purchased by households (personal consumption), by businesses (investment), by the government, and by foreign buyers (exports). However, domestic consumers and firms also purchase goods and services from abroad. Since the data on consumption and investment does not distinguish between goods and services bought from abroad, imports must be subtracted. 

This subtraction does not imply that imports reduce economic activity. Instead, it corrects for the fact that imported goods are already included in the consumption and investment data. Without the adjustment, GDP would overstate domestic production by including foreign output.

Imports and front-loaded demand
Consider, for example, a household purchasing European wine ahead of expected tariffs. The purchase raises consumption expenditure, contributing positively to GDP. But because the wine is imported, it also raises imports, which are subtracted. These two effects cancel out, leaving GDP unchanged. The same logic applies to a firm increasing its imports of vehicles or equipment for inventory purposes: the purchase boosts investment, but this is offset by the corresponding import entry.

In both cases, imports enter the GDP calculation with a negative sign, but only to remove the foreign-produced component of domestic spending. The increase in imports does not exert an independent, negative impact on measured output.

The broader picture
Imports themselves do not directly reduce GDP. For imports to weigh on economic output, they must displace spending on domestically produced goods and services. This dynamic may have been at play in Q1, when final sales of domestic product declined by 2.5% even as final sales to domestic purchasers rose by 2.3%. One possible explanation is that firms and consumers diverted spending towards imported goods, leaving less room in their budgets for domestic purchases.

Another possibility is that the announcement of new tariffs introduced a wave of uncertainty, prompting households and businesses to hold back on most forms of spending - except for imports expected to rise sharply in price. This interpretation reconciles the strong import demand with the drop in domestic output and is consistent with the collapse in consumer sentiment observed during the quarter. That said, it is too early to draw firm conclusions, and subsequent data may shed further light on the underlying dynamics.  

Required

Required

Required

Required

Required

Required

Required

Required

Please note you can manage your subscriptions by visiting the Preferences link in the emails you receive from us.

Required